AllDomestic Trade Frictions and AgricultureSebastian SoteloUniversity of MichiganI afor thmousCalieHelleSalgain semneapUniveUniveBureathis pcussioper wElectro[...

1 answer below »



Based on what you have learned throughout this course; summarize and critically analyze the work of Sebastian Sotelo titled ‘Domestic Trade Frictions and Agriculture’ and prepare it for submission for the Hypothetical Journal of Political Economy


All Domestic Trade Frictions and Agriculture Sebastian Sotelo University of Michigan I a for th mous Calie Helle Salga in sem neap Unive Unive Burea this p cussio per w Electro [ Journa © 2020 use su I develop a model of agriculture on heterogeneous land to study the relation between trade, productivity, and welfare in Peru, where far- mers face high internal and external trade costs. I quantify the model with new data on crop prices, yields, and land allocations. I then mea- sure the effects of changes to trade opportunities. A policy of paving roads raises aggregate productivity (4.9%) and the median farmer’s welfare (2.7%), but increased competition from remote suppliers harms 20% of farmers. An increase in international grain prices spreads unevenly across regions, benefiting farmers but hurting urban consumers close to ports. I. Introduction In developing countries, a large majority of the poor live in rural areas. Their livelihoods are often tied to subsistence agriculture, limited by ma- jor barriers to trade, such as weak infrastructure, adverse geography, and m indebted to Sam Kortum, Nancy Stokey, Thomas Chaney, and Andrei Levchenko eir advice and encouragement. I also thank the editor (Ali Hortaçsu), three anony- referees, Fernando Alvarez, Costas Arkolakis, David Atkin, Saki Bigio, Lorenzo ndo, Kerem Cosar, Javier Cravino, Alan Deardorff, Jonathan Eaton, Jeremy Fox, Sara r, Erik Hurst, Gita Khun Jush, Joaquin Lopez, Sara Moreira, Ralph Ossa, Edgar do, Danny Tannenbaum, Adriaan Ten Kate, and Mike Waugh, as well as participants inars at the University of Chicago, Yale University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Min- olis, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the University of Michigan, Penn State rsity, the Federal Reserve Board, Drexel University, the University of Toronto, Brown rsity, DePaul University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, and the National u of Economic Research for helpful comments and suggestions at different stages of roject. Special thanks to Alan Sanchez, Ben Faber, and Thibault Fally for detailed dis- ns. Maria Alejandra Zegarra provided excellent research assistance. Part of this pa- as written while I was visiting the Economics Department at Yale University. Funding nically published June 3, 2020 l of Political Economy, 2020, vol. 128, no. 7] by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2020/12807-0006$10.00 2690 This content downloaded from 099.230.201.231 on July 25, 2020 07:00:20 AM bject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c). domestic trade frictions and agriculture 2691 the spatial dispersion characteristic of rural populations. Not surprisingly, researchers and policy makers perceive the costs of domestic and interna- tional trade as a drag on incomes and productivity.1 Assessing the welfare and productivity effects of improvements in trade opportunities, such as infrastructure, requires an understanding of how individual farmers and consumers react to these improvements and how their choices interact in the aggregate. On one hand, policies that reduce trade costs can increase allocative efficiency and welfare by unlocking the forces of comparative advantage and the use of modern inputs. On the other hand, such policies also affect the equilibriumprices of crops, espe- cially those that are traded only domestically, thereby potentially harming producers who face increased competition. Because these crops usually constitute an important part of the diet of food buyers, improved ex- change opportunities can also affect welfare through their effect on con- sumption prices. In this paper, I develop a framework to measure the consequences of trade-related shocks to the agricultural sector and quantify it using Peruvian data. I start by documenting four facts about agriculture in Peru that guide my modeling choices. First, there is substantial price disper- sion across regions, which is indicative of domestic trade costs. Consistent with the presence of domestic and international trade, prices are also higher in urban areas, and the prices of export crops rise with proximity to ports. Second, farmers within a region allocate land tomany crops, and third, average revenue per unit of land varies substantially across crops. These last two facts suggest that land quality varies within regions and that land intensity differs across crops. Fourth, the quality of roads varies through- out the country, which produces spatial variation in trade costs. Informed by these facts, I then develop a quantitative model of special- ization and trade. In the model, farmers can grow various crops on land plots of varying quality. They can also trade their crops, at a cost, for in- termediate inputs, nonagricultural goods, and other crops in local, ur- ban, and internationalmarkets. Differences in land quality across regions and in land intensity across crops generate domestic and international 1 According to the World Bank’s (2007) World Development Report, as of 2002, 75% of the world’s poor were rural dwellers. The same report relates developing countries’ agricultural performance to within-country variation in access to markets and land quality (World Bank 2007, 54). Likewise, a recent Inter-American Development Bank report addresses how transport costs limit overall exporting activity: “High domestic transport costs can push exports to concentrate in just a few areas . . . while squeezing gains or simply locking out of trade large swaths of the country” (Mesquita Moreira et al. 2013, 3). from the Sjaastad Research Fellowship Fund is gratefully acknowledged. Finally, I thank Ministerio de Transportes y Comunicaciones de Peru and Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego de Peru for sharing their data with me. All opinions and any remaining errors are my own. This paper circulated previously as “Trade Frictions and Agricultural Productivity: Theory and Evidence from Peru.” Data are provided as supplementary material online. This content downloaded from 099.230.201.231 on July 25, 2020 07:00:20 AM All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c). 2692 journal of political economy All trade, while domestic trade costs discourage it. The resultingmodel is a hy- brid between a small open economy, which takes international prices as given, and a closed economy, in which prices are determined by regional trade within the country. The equilibrium features price dispersion and in- complete land specialization across regions, as in the data. Productivity and welfare, moreover, are determined by market access and comparative advantage. To quantify the theory, I construct a novel data set that combines sev- eral sources of data on Peruvian agriculture. I use government statistics on land allocation, production, and prices to estimate crop-specific land quality across and within regions. To estimate within-country trade fric- tions, I bring in a complete data set of the transportation system of Peru. Finally, I use disaggregated household survey data to estimate the elastic- ity of substitution across crops in consumption. I next conduct two sets of counterfactual experiments to understand and quantify how changes in trade opportunities affect welfare and pro- ductivity in the context of imperfect regional integration. First, informed by policy plans of the Ministry of Transportation of Peru, I simulate two infrastructure shocks that improve the transportation system and reduce domestic trade costs unevenly across regions. Second, I simulate a shock to international crop prices based on a World Bank scenario for the ef- fects of the Doha trade talks. There are two key points to understanding regional responses in these counterfactual scenarios. First, the initial production and consumption allocations govern the extent to which changes in prices translate into changes in productivity and welfare; these allocations, in turn, are driven by the interaction of comparative advantage and market access. Second, equilibrium prices respond endogenously and transmit shocks across re- gions. These price responses also depend on the substitutability of crops in production—which is linked to the degree of land heterogeneity—and in consumption. To understand, for example, how improved transportation directly im- pacts farmers’ productivity and welfare, note that when access to markets is costly, farmers pay high prices for their purchases and collect low prices for their sales. By reducing the cost of accessing domestic and foreignmar- kets, better roads allow farmers to specialize according to comparative ad- vantage and increase their use of imported intermediate inputs. The general equilibrium effects of this policy are more subtle. While infrastructure policy increases the price that a farmer gets for his prod- ucts by improving his own access to domestic and international markets, the policy also improves the access of farmers in other regions and in- creases the supply of crops to domestic markets, thus decreasing their price. Increased competition from remote suppliers therefore leads to re- duced prices for farmers who originally had better access to markets. This content downloaded from 099.230.201.231 on July 25, 2020 07:00:20 AM use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c). domestic trade frictions and agriculture 2693 Using this quantitative model, I measure the aggregate and distribu- tional effects of two infrastructure policies. I find that a Ministry of Trans- portation plan to pave major roads increases productivity in agriculture, measured as a multicrop index of productivity (3.8% for the average re- gion and 4.9% in aggregate). Themedian farmer, moreover, experiences a 2.7%welfare gain. There is also substantial heterogeneity: the farmer in the 25th percentile of the welfare change distribution gains 0.1%, and the farmer in the 75th percentile gains 13.2%. Rural dwellers employed in the nonagricultural sector mostly benefit as a result of the policy, but their gains are limited in remote areas because consumption prices in- crease and their ability to export nonagricultural goods is limited. Along the same lines, a different policy of building new roads in targeted re- mote areas allows the median farmer to gain 0.02% of welfare, while far- mers at the 25th percentile of the welfare gains distribution lose 0.1% and those at the 75th percentile experience 0.25% gains. In both simulated policies, an increased supply of crops not traded internationally drives down the welfare of farmers who were originally well connected to urban markets.2 In the second counterfactual exercise, I simulate a shock to interna- tional crop prices based on a World Bank analysis of the potential effects of the Doha trade talks. This exogenous shock mildly increases the inter- national price of cereals and cotton. Unlike in a small open economy, however, international shocks are unevenly spread in regional markets because many Home regions do not trade every crop with the rest of the world. Although this is a relatively small shock, its general equilibrium effects are quantitatively important and lead to the opposite welfare pre- diction of a simple small open economy model in about 23% of regions. Proximity to ports makes it more likely that a region will trade with the rest of the world and therefore strengthens the transmission of interna- tional price shocks to regionalmarkets—including to crops that are traded only domestically. Among nonagricultural workers, those in regions close toports tend to losemore, because their consumptionbasketsmore closely reflect the price increase of high-consumption cereals. In addition to producing substantive results for Peru, this paper also makes three methodological contributions. First, the theory connects tightly with data on land allocations and productivity; hence, the model can be estimated based solely on agricultural and aggregate trade statis- tics, which are collected by many countries. This approach is especially useful for studying economies in which trade also occurs within borders, because it sidesteps the need to use domestic trade data, which are typi- cally unavailable. 2 Sizable welfare reductions are not uncommon, even though both policies reduce trade costs for all regions. The farmer in the 5th percentile of the welfare gains distribution loses 2.4% in the first policy and 0.7% in the second. This content downloaded from 099.230.201.231 on July 25, 2020 07:00:20 AM All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c). 2694 journal of political economy All Second, themodel treats each crop as a homogeneous good, instead of using the standardArmingtonmodeling device in which the same good is regionally differentiated. This approach allows for a simple analysis of the dissemination of price shocks across regional markets—using only data on initial consumption and land shares—and the elasticities of supply and demand. Moreover, when studying trade within a country, this treat- ment provides an alternative to regional differentiation, which, besides being implausible at high spatial resolutions, forces all regions to trade bilaterally in all goods. In contrast, the model in this paper generates sparse trade patterns—a well-known feature of trade data—using finite trade costs. Third, I obtain a simple estimating equation for the elasticity of land allocation with respect to relative prices, which is a key quantity that gov- erns adjustments to shocks. The estimating equation captures a basic eco- nomic intuition inherent to models in which production factors are het- erogeneous—namely, that factors are optimally allocated to their best use. Hence, increasing a crop’s land allocation reduces yields because it re- quires incorporating land less suited to that use. The strength of this effect is directly related to the heterogeneity of land. This parameter also governs all cross-elasticies in production—a practical compromise when the num- ber of parameters that can be estimated is limited by the availability of a few cross sections of data. Peru is an ideal setting for this study, because its geography is diverse and its agricultural sector resembles that of both developed and develop- ing countries. It is a middle-income country in which a few large urban markets are often the destination for traded agricultural produce but some well-connected regions produce for export markets.
Answered 2 days AfterDec 19, 2022

Answer To: AllDomestic Trade Frictions and AgricultureSebastian SoteloUniversity of MichiganI afor...

Ayan answered on Dec 22 2022
34 Votes
WRITTEN ASSIGNMENT        3
WRITTEN ASSIGNMENT
Abstract
    The study evaluates Sebastian Sotelo's model for the speculative diary of political economy, "Domestic Trade Frictions and Agriculture." In this methodology, the discussed model provides a solid and straightforward condition for crop pay distribution and land allocation. In doing as such, the iceberg definition technique and the model of trade cost were both used. By doing this, the specifics of the transportation industry are kept away from. The model has been evaluated by information from land locations, yields, and crop prices during the investigation, using the new information. In this advanced global market and trade opportunities, the consequences based on changes in conditions of technological adoption and globalization of international commerce have also been made sense of. Through the program of clearing roads, it has been noticed that general creation increased by 4.9% while farmer welfare increased by 2.7%. In any case, the in
creasing competitiveness has affected 20% of farmers in isolated areas. At last, an increase in grain prices and other agricultural prices globally is unevenly distributed, as farmers profit while consumers close to ports suffer.
Table of contents
Abstract    2
Introduction    4
Information about agricultural production, consumption, and roads as well as the reasons for the research    6
Farm gate and consumer pricing differ geographically    7
Diverse crops' geographic ranges and growth    10
Analysis and criticism of soil, technology, and land use for agriculture productivity    12
Conclusion    19
References    22
Introduction
    Subsistence agriculture is the primary source of payment for the larger part of the impoverished individuals who reside in emerging countries. It is vital to assess the productivity and welfare implications of trade advancement possibilities, such as infrastructure, yet doing so requires knowledge of how customers and individual farmers will respond to such improvements in terms of their purchasing decisions. By releasing the forces of similar benefit and using current farming inputs, policies that lower trade costs can further develop welfare and allocative efficiency in this situation. Again, these rules really do affect agricultural harmony prices, especially for domestically added crops, which hurt farmers who are facing increasing contest. In this research, a procedure for measuring the effects of trade shocks on the agriculture sector has been established, and it is applied to information from Peru. By utilizing modeling options, the creator begins by presenting facts in regard to agriculture in Peru. These facts are consistent with the wide price range across the area, farmers' use of several crops, the assortment in land quality inside regions, and the variety in street conditions across the country, all of which add to spatial heterogeneity in terms of trade costs. Using such real data, the creator made a quantitative model of specialization and commerce. To evaluate, the creator made a special informational index that incorporates several sources of data on Perun agriculture. To evaluate and grasp how changes in trade opportunities impact welfare and productivity in a situation of defective regional joining, the creator also completed two sets of counterfactual experiments. As well as furnishing Peru with useful results, the report offers three systemic advances. To start with, the hypothesis closely relates to information on productivity and land allocations, consequently, the model might be simply estimated based on aggregated trade and agricultural statistics that are assembled by numerous nations, giving an opportunity to study economics. The second contrast is that the model regards each crop as a homogenous decent as opposed to utilizing Armington's conventional model, which differentiates the same thing locally. The creator was ready to establish a straightforward estimating condition for the elasticity of land allocation with respect to relative prices, which is essentially an urgent element controlling shock adjustments. Peru was an extraordinary contender for this study because it is a middle-pay country with a diversified geography, and an agricultural sector that is similar to both created and immature countries, and both. Peru also has a small number of significant metropolitan marketplaces that are frequently used as destinations for agricultural products with connections to export markets. Once more, there are current highways beside soil and rock roads. Geographical and transportation factors impact market access in Peru since conveying crops is expensive. Similar to immature nations, 25% of the labor force in Peru is taken part in agriculture. The article is associated with different works on harmony trade models in agriculture, including those by Svanidze and Götz, (2019) among others. These scientists investigate the role that trade opportunities play in lessening the adverse consequences of environmental change, improving well-being, and advancing structural change. Again, the research advances writing by offering a system for inspecting pricing and allocations when areas that produce homogenous items are strongly associated with each other and the global economy. Albeit the overall harmony structure of the model deviates from previous work and offers novel insights into regional response to trade shocks, the modeling components have significant importance in Peru and, of course, other non-industrial nations. Again, the article relates to projections for land shares across crops, so the research essentially allows the researcher to connect to land use information for national commerce. In the past, several studies have analyzed the effects of transportation policy in various contexts for various purposes. In any case, the research focuses on how infrastructure policy and international price shocks impact the agriculture industry. The impact of such shocks on the distribution of welfare to space and its employees is also evaluated objectively. By and large, the article demonstrates that in non-industrial countries, transportation technology is a barrier to using contemporary inputs, and that assuming this technology is improved, it might result in a more effective allocation of labor and land resources.
Information about agricultural production, consumption, and roads as well as the reasons for the research
    To measure the costs of transportation as well as Peru's creation and consumption, four key informational collections have been consolidated in this article. 20 crops were analyzed by the researcher using the information on the worth of creation across the whole country and the 194 provinces of Peru. Furthermore, information from the Global Agro-Ecological Zones (GAEZ), the National Household Survey (ENAHO), and national agricultural statistics were accumulated (SISAGRI). Since Perun roads are split into rural roads, departmental roads, and national roads, the geography and transportation statistics were taken from the Ministry of Transport report for every street's length, area, and quality (Donovan & Kevin, 2018). Four elements are the main impetuses behind the modeling strategy used in this research. The first is that Peru's roads differ in quality across the country, which causes regional variations in trade prices. The other element is that various crops are filled in better places, which demonstrates the fluctuation of land quality. Indicators of inward trade barriers remember consistent and significant disparities in agricultural prices among regions and among rural and metropolitan areas. Last but not least, the normal pay per unit of land varies decisively amongst crops, showing that various crops need various intensities. The model has also been measured through information on land locations, yields, and crop prices during the research using the new information. In this cutting-edge global market and trade opportunities, the consequences based on changes in conditions of technological adoption and globalization of international commerce have also been made sense of. Through the program of clearing roads, it has been noticed that general creation increased by 4.9% while farmer welfare increased by 2.7%. In any case, the increasing competitiveness has affected 20% of farmers in isolated areas. In conclusion, an increase in the price of grains and different products all through the world has a lopsided distribution of benefits among farmers and consumers who live close to ports. The readers of your diary will probably find these findings interesting. We affirm that this composing is our own, that it has never been published, and that it is not presently being considered for distribution elsewhere else.
Farm gate and consumer pricing differ geographically
    The figures beneath use espresso, one of Peru's fundamental exports, to give examples of variances in farm gate pricing between areas. Figures below, B illustrates that the fall in farm gate prices is connected with the distance to the capital, which possesses the primary seaport. Figure A depicts the wide variations in espresso prices across the regions of creation. The unit values got from the household surveys was used to assess assuming that prices in the space are systematically unique. The results of regression calculations utilizing two elective sets of dummies are shown in Table 1. Segment 1 of the joint significance test for commonplace dummies displays the F-statistics of a joint significance test for each crop. The invalid hypothesis is disregarded by each crop, and these dummies need logical power, to demonstrate geographical dispersion. A significant part of the price fluctuation is geographical, as shown by the regression of R2 esteem in section 2. Columns 3 and 4 of the report give the coefficient and standard blunder, respectively. On the off chance that the information is in association with metropolitan regions, these columns display regressing log...
SOLUTION.PDF

Answer To This Question Is Available To Download

Related Questions & Answers

More Questions »

Submit New Assignment

Copy and Paste Your Assignment Here