‘Another thing’ paper (20%) – On Sept. 13, we are reading ‘Thing 1’ from Ha-Joon Chang’s book 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism. For this paper, I would like you to choose one of the...

1 answer below »



‘Another thing’ paper (20%) – On Sept. 13, we are reading ‘Thing 1’ from Ha-Joon Chang’s book 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism. For this paper, I would like you to choose one of the other 22 things from that book (which can be found on Brightspace in Documents) as the focus of your paper.

Your goal will be to extend the lessons Chang presents in your chosen chapter to a different example/context.


For example, if you chose Thing 8 (“Capital has a nationality”), perhaps you decide to examine a specific TNC (or two) and why it matters what the nationality of that capital is. This isn’t the only way to use Thing 8, of course, and

exactly what you will argue and how you will extend the idea

if part of your assignment! You should use at least 5 sources (not counting Chang’s book), at least two of which should be from our course. The paper should be in the range of 1200-1500 words and is due no later than 11:59pm on October 16th











‘Another thing’ paper (20%) – On Sept. 13, we are reading ‘Thing 1’ from Ha-Joon Chang’s book 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism. For this paper, I would like you to choose one of the other 22 things from that book (which can be found on Brightspace in Documents) as the focus of your paper. Your goal will be to extend the lessons Chang presents in your chosen chapter to a different example/context. For example, if you chose Thing 8 (“Capital has a nationality”), perhaps you decide to examine a specific TNC (or two) and why it matters what the nationality of that capital is. This isn’t the only way to use Thing 8, of course, and exactly what you will argue and how you will extend the idea if part of your assignment! You should use at least 5 sources (not counting Chang’s book), at least two of which should be from our course. The paper should be in the range of 1200-1500 words and is due no later than 11:59pm on October 16th Need 5 sources above the actual article / chapter we’re reading. If you are not even sure what capitalism is, read: Things 1, 2, 5, 8, 13, 16, 19, 20, and 22  Thing 5 Assume the worst about people and you get the worst Assume the worst about people and you get the worst  · Capitalism · Neoliberalism · The market · Government intervention What they tell you  Adam Smith famously said: ‘It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.’ The market beautifully harnesses the energy of selfish individuals thinking only of themselves (and, at most, their families) to produce social harmony. Communism failed because it denied this human instinct and ran the economy assuming everyone to be selfless, or at least largely altruistic. We have to assume the worst about people (that is, they only think about themselves), if we are to construct a durable economic system.  · https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/volokh-conspiracy/wp/2017/11/07/lessons-from-a-century-of-communism/ (why communism failed) What they don’t tell you  Self-interest is a most powerful trait in most human beings. However, it’s not our only drive. It is very often not even our primary motivation. Indeed, if the world were full of the selfseeking individuals found in economics textbooks, it would grind to a halt because we would be spending most of our time cheating, trying to catch the cheaters, and punishing the caught. The world works as it does only because people are not the totally self-seeking agents that free-market economics believes them to be. We need to design an economic system that, while acknowledging that people are often selfish, exploits other human motives to the full and gets the best out of people. The likelihood is that, if we assume the worst about people, we will get the worst out of them.  How (not) to run a company In the mid 1990s, I was attending a conference in Japan on the ‘East Asian growth miracle’, organized by the World Bank. On one side of the debate were people like myself, arguing that government intervention had played a positive role in the East Asian growth story by going against market signals and protecting and subsidizing industries such as automobiles and electronics. On the other side, there were economists supporting the World Bank, who argued that government intervention had at best been an irrelevant sideshow or at worst done more harm than good in East Asia. More importantly, they added, even if it were true that the East Asian miracle owed something to government intervention, that does not mean that policies used by the East Asian countries can be recommended to other countries. Government officials who make policies are (like all of us) self-seeking agents, it was pointed out, more interested in expanding their own power and prestige rather than promoting national interests. They argued that government intervention worked in East Asia only because they had exceptionally selfless and capable bureaucrats for historical reasons (which we need not go into here). Even some of the economists who were supporting an active role for government conceded this point.  · https://www.investopedia.com/articles/economics/11/how-governments-influence-markets.asp (government influence on the markets)  Listening to this debate, a distinguished-looking Japanese gentleman in the audience raised his hand. Introducing himself as one of the top managers of Kobe Steel, the then fourth-largest steel producer in Japan, the gentleman chided the economists for misunderstanding the nature of modern bureaucracy, be it in the government or in the private sector The Kobe Steel manager said (I am, of course, paraphrasing him): ‘I am sorry to say this, but you economists don’t understand how the real world works. I have a PhD in metallurgy and have been working in Kobe Steel for nearly three decades, so I know a thing or two about steel-making. However, my company is now so large and complex that even I do not understand more than half the things that are going on within it. As for the other managers – with backgrounds in accounting and marketing – they really haven’t much of a clue. Despite this, our board of directors routinely approves the majority of projects submitted by our employees, because we believe that our employees work for the good of the company. If we assumed that everyone is out to promote his own interests and questioned the motivations of our employees all the time, the company would grind to a halt, as we would spend all our time going through proposals that we really don’t understand. You simply cannot run a large bureaucratic organization, be it Kobe Steel or your government, if you assume that everyone is out for himself.’ This is merely an anecdote, but it is a powerful testimony to the limitations of standard economic theory, which assumes that self-interest is the only human motivation that counts. Let me elaborate.  Selfish butchers and bakers Free-market economics starts from the assumption that all economic agents are selfish, as summed up in Adam Smith’s assessment of the butcher, the brewer and the baker. The beauty of the market system, they contend, is that it channels what seems to be the worst aspect of human nature – self-seeking, or greed, if you like – into something productive and socially beneficial.  Given their selfish nature, shopkeepers will try to overcharge you, workers will try their best to goof off from work, and professional managers will try to maximize their own salaries and prestige rather than profits, which go to the shareholders rather than themselves. However, the power of the market will put strict limits to, if not completely eliminate, these behaviours: shopkeepers won’t cheat you if they have a competitor around the corner; workers would not dare to slack off if they know they can be easily replaced; hired managers will not be able to fleece the shareholders if they operate in a vibrant stock market, which will ensure that managers who generate lower profits, and thus lower share prices, risk losing their jobs through takeover.  To free-market economists, public officials – politicians and government bureaucrats – pose a unique challenge in this regard. Their pursuit of self-interest cannot be restrained to any meaningful degree because they are not subject to market discipline. Politicians do face some competition from each other, but elections happen so infrequently that their disciplinary effects are limited. Consequently, there is plenty of scope for them to pursue policies that heighten their power and wealth, at the cost of national welfare. When it comes to the career bureaucrats, the scope for selfseeking is even greater. Even if their political masters, the politicians, try to make them implement policies that cater to electoral demands, they can always obfuscate and manipulate the politicians, as was so brilliantly depicted in the BBC comedy series Yes, Minister and its sequel, Yes, Prime Minister. Moreover, unlike the politicians, these career bureaucrats have high job security, if not lifetime tenure, so they can wait out their political masters by simply delaying things. This is the crux of the concerns that the World Bank economists were expressing in the meeting in Japan that Imentioned at the beginning of this Thing.  Therefore, free-market economists recommend, the portion of the economy controlled by politicians and bureaucrats should be minimized. Deregulation and privatization, in this view, are not only economically efficient but also politically sensible in that they minimize the very possibility that public officials can use the state as a vehicle to promote their own self-interests, at the cost of the general public. Some – the so-called ‘New Public Management’school – go even further and recommend that the management of the government itself should be exposed to greater market forces: a more aggressive use of performance-related pay and short-term contracts for bureaucrats; more frequent contracting-out of government services; a more active exchange of personnel between the public and the private sectors.  We may not be angels, but…. The assumption of self-seeking individualism, which is at the foundation of free-market economics, has a lot of resonance with our personal experiences. We have all been cheated by unscrupulous traders, be it the fruit seller who put some rotten plums at the bottom of the paper bag or the yoghurt company that vastly exaggerated the health benefits of it products. We know too many corrupt politicians and lazy bureaucrats to believe that all public servants are solely serving the public. Most of us, myself included, have goofed off from work ourselves and some of us have been frustrated by junior colleagues and assistants who find all kinds of excuses not to put in serious work. Moreover, what we read in the news media these days tells us that professional managers, even the supposed champions of shareholder interest such as Jack Welch of GE and Rick Wagoner of GM, have not really been serving the best interests of the shareholders (see Thing 2).  This is all true. However, we also have a lot of evidence – not just anecdotes but systematic evidence – showing that self-interest is not the only human motivation that matters even in our economic life. Self-interest, to be sure, is one of the most important, but we have many other motives – honesty, self-respect, altruism, love, sympathy, faith, sense of duty, solidarity, loyalty, public-spiritedness, patriotism, and so on – that are sometimes even more important than selfseeking as the driver of our behaviours.1  Our earlier example of Kobe Steel shows how successful companies are run on trust and loyalty, rather than suspicion and self-seeking. If you think this is a peculiar example from a country of ‘worker ants’ that suppresses individuality against human nature, pick up any book on business leadership or any autobiography by a successful businessman published in the West and see what they say. Do they say
Answered Same DayOct 14, 2022

Answer To: ‘Another thing’ paper (20%) – On Sept. 13, we are reading ‘Thing 1’ from Ha-Joon Chang’s book 23...

Prince answered on Oct 15 2022
45 Votes
Introduction
“Big government makes people more open to change”. This is one of the claims made by Ha-Joon Chang, a well-known Guardian columnist and professor at Cambridge's Political Economy of Development, in "Thing 21" of his book "23 Things They Don't Tell You About Capitalism." In this book, Cha
ng challenges conventional economic thinking and provides a fresh perspective on understanding global economic thought. The 23 items represent a diverse range of economic theories. from overused statements like "There is no such thing as a "free" market," to stranger claims like "the washing machine has transformed the world more than the internet has," Chang offers a thorough critique of free markets and globalisation in the book.
The book is intended for a large readership. It is simple to read and accessible to a wider audience than only academic economists. One of the questionable aspects of the work is the fact that he used so few sources as references. I'll delve more deeply into one of Chang's 23 points in this piece. "Big government increases people's receptivity to change," says Thing 21.
Chang’s Statement
This essay is on Thing 21 from Chang's book. This statement's main takeaway is that Neo-Classical economists contend that the incentive to labour is significantly diminished in welfare states with substantial social security programmes. This is as a result of the respectable reservation choice. Not all of the wealth is lost when you lose your work. Unemployment will result from the diminished incentive to work, having a negative effect. Chang disputes this, claiming that people are more willing to take risks when there is a social safety net in place. And this will lead to a more efficient allocation of skilled individuals within an economy.
Chang makes a point of illustrating this by bringing up two distinct nations. Both nations will display a protest against the traditional economic way of thinking. He begins with the USA, which has a weak safety net. It's simple to fire employees, and the pay is either nonexistent or extremely poor. This leads me to the conclusion that being dismissed also results in losing health insurance. Following his discussion of this incident, he moves on to the South Korean situation, where the government sought to create a flexible labour market by lowering job security. But the opposite occurred, not the labour market becoming more flexible. Korean students opted for "sunset" careers like driving cars since they carry no danger. The kids' lack of selection of "sunrise" creates a concern for the future. These are riskier occupations, such as bioengineering. Chang draws the conclusion that lessening job security does have a detrimental impact on a flexible market that requires more risk-takers.
Hu-Joon Chang’s opinion
The central contention of "Things 21" is whether or not security nets, or unemployment benefits in a larger sense, are required to achieve low unemployment. Security nets come in many forms, including universal...
SOLUTION.PDF

Answer To This Question Is Available To Download

Related Questions & Answers

More Questions »

Submit New Assignment

Copy and Paste Your Assignment Here